1
The New York Times, June 19, 2011
Seriously, Some Consensus About Health Care
By N. GREGORY MANKIW
WE are entering the season of polarization. With various Republicans vying
to replace Barack Obama, the president eager to keep his job, and both the
House and the Senate up for grabs, candidates from both sides of the aisle
will spend the next year and a half stressing their differences.
But beneath this veneer of partisanship lie a few fundamental agreements.
Consider health care, which will be at the center of the political debate.
Here are four aspects of the issue in which Republicans and Democrats
have stumbled into consensus.
THE VALUE OF COMPETITION
Representative Paul D. Ryan,
Republican of Wisconsin, has attracted much attention with his plan to
reform Medicare. He proposes replacing the current fee-for-service
program, in which the government picks up the bill for medical expenses,
with a “premium-support” system in which seniors use federal dollars to
choose among competing private insurance plans.
Democratic critics of the plan suggest that enacting it would be akin to
pushing Grandma over a cliff. But they rarely point out that the premiumsupport
model is in some ways similar to the system set up under President
Obama’s health care law. If choosing among competing private plans on a
government-regulated exchange is a good idea for someone at age 50, why
is it so horrific for someone who is 70?
Republicans, meanwhile, are eager to repeal Obamacare and so are also
reluctant to point out its parallels with Ryancare. We can take heart,
however, in the kernel of agreement about the value of private competition.
THE INSURANCE MANDATE
Perhaps the most controversial piece of
the Obama plan is the mandate for individuals to have health insurance.
But think for a moment about what this really means. No one has proposed
putting the uninsured in jail. Instead, those without insurance will be fined.
A mandate is just a financial incentive to have insurance.
2
What is the Republican alternative for having more people insured? It is
unclear what the Republicans would do if they ever succeeded in repealing
the health care reform law. However, their last presidential nominee —
Senator John McCain — proposed a tax credit for buying health insurance.
That may seem more palatable than a mandate, because it uses a carrot
rather than a stick.
But consider who would pay for that tax credit. The answer is all taxpayers.
This tax burden would be particularly hard on the uninsured, who would
face higher taxes without enjoying the credit’s benefit. In other words,
giving a tax credit to those who buy insurance is a back-door way to impose
fines on those who don’t.
TAXING THE RICH
Democrats want to increase taxes on the rich to
fund the looming fiscal gap, which is driven largely by soaring health costs.
Republicans object, saying higher taxes create economic distortions,
discourage work and impede growth. Last month, John A. Boehner, the
House speaker, said that we should instead consider means-testing
Medicare. But what does that mean?
Here is how means-testing might work. We could start by choosing some
income threshold — say, $250,000 — and then require people over 65 with
higher annual income to pay more in Medicare premiums than they do
now. For example, for every $1,000 of income beyond the threshold, they
might have to pay an extra $10 in annual premiums.
Sounds good, right? But notice that the economic effects of means-testing
are much the same as a tax increase. This particular plan is like increasing
the income tax rate by one percentage point for high-income seniors. It is
only semantics as to whether the $10 is called a “tax” or a “premium.”
Indeed, means-testing could create more economic distortions than would
broad-based tax increases. Seniors have more flexibility in how much they
work than do typical Americans. In particular, for many people, the timing
of retirement is discretionary. The higher marginal tax rates implicit in
means-testing will induce people to leave the labor force earlier than they
3
otherwise would. This would deprive the economy of some of its most
experienced and productive workers.
BLINKERED OPTIMISM
Democrats and Republicans generally have
different approaches to controlling the growth of health care spending.
Democrats often favor a top-down approach: a panel of experts set up by
the recent health care law will decide which medical procedures are costeffective
and which are wasteful. Republicans tend to prefer a bottom-up
approach: empower consumers to make their own choices, they say, and
the power of competition among private providers will keep costs down.
One thing that the two parties share, however, is the belief that controlling
health care costs is possible. Yet many economists believe that the rise in
health spending is largely the result of medical advances, which prolong
and enhance life at a high cost. Perhaps health spending will inevitably, and
even should, keep rising as a share of national income.
This possibility raises a question: If health care becomes an increasing
share of the economy, how will we allocate it, and how will we pay for it?
That is, if controlling the cost of health care fails, what is Plan B?
That is a question that candidates from both political parties agree on as
well: they all seem determined to avoid it.
1
The New York Times, May 7, 2011
If You Have the Answers, Tell Me
By N. GREGORY MANKIW
AFTER more than a quarter-century as a professional economist, I
have a confession to make: There is a lot I don’t know about the economy.
Indeed, the area of economics where I have devoted most of my energy and
attention — the ups and downs of the business cycle — is where I find
myself most often confronting important questions without obvious
answers.
Now, if you follow economic commentary in the newspapers or the
blogosphere, you have probably not run into many humble economists. By
its nature, punditry craves attention, which is easier to attract with
certainties than with equivocation.
But that certitude reflects bravado more often than true knowledge.
So let me come clean and highlight three questions that perplex me. The
answers to them may well shape the economy in the years to come.
How long will it take for the economy’s wounds to heal?
When President Obama took office in 2009, his economic team
projected a quick recovery from the recession the nation was experiencing.
The administration’s first official forecast said economic growth, computed
from fourth quarter to fourth quarter, would average 3.5 percent in 2010
and 4.4 percent in 2011. Unemployment was supposed to fall to 7.7 percent
by the end of 2010 and to 6.8 percent by the end of 2011.
The reality has turned out not nearly as rosy. Growth was only 2.8
percent last year, and the first quarter of this year came in at a meager rate
of 1.8 percent. Unemployment, meanwhile, lingers well above 8 percent,
and according to Ben S. Bernanke, the Federal Reserve chairman, is
expected to keep doing so throughout this year.
Economists will long debate whether President Obama’s policies are
to blame or the patient was just sicker than his economists realized. But
there is no doubt that the pace of this recovery will come nowhere close to
2
matching the one achieved after the last deep recession, when President
Ronald Reagan presided over a fall in the unemployment rate from 10.8
percent in December 1982 to 7.3 percent two years later.
Looking ahead, an open issue is whether the recession will leave scars
that prevent a return to jobless rates that were considered normal just a few
years ago. A striking feature of today’s labor market is the rise of long-term
joblessness. The average duration of unemployment is now almost 40
weeks, about twice what it reached in previous recessions. The long-term
unemployed may well lose job skills and find their future prospects
permanently impaired. But because we are in uncharted waters, it is hard
for anyone to be sure.
How long will inflation expectations remain anchored?
In 1967, Milton Friedman gave an address to the American Economic
Association with this simple but profound message: The inflation rate that
the economy gets is, in large measure, based on the inflation rate that
people expect. When everyone expects high inflation, workers bargain hard
for wage increases, and companies push prices higher to keep up with the
projected cost increases. When everyone expects inflation to be benign,
workers and companies are less aggressive. In short, the perception of
inflation — or of the lack of it — creates the reality.
Although novel when Professor Friedman proposed it, his theory is
now textbook economics, and is at the heart of Federal Reserve policy. Fed
policy makers are keeping interest rates low, despite soaring commodity
prices. Why? Inflation expectations are “well anchored,” we are told, so
there is no continuing problem with inflation. Rising gasoline prices are
just a transitory blip.
They are probably right, but there is still reason to wonder. Even if
expectations are as important as the conventional canon presumes, it isn’t
obvious what determines those expectations. Are people merely backwardlooking,
extrapolating recent experience into the future? Or are the
expectations based on the credibility of policy makers? And if credibility
matters, how is it established? Are people making rational judgments, or
are they easily overcome by fear and influenced by extraneous events?
Mr. Bernanke and his team may learn that, in turbulent times,
expectations can become unmoored more easily than they think.
3
How long will the bond market trust the United States?
A remarkable feature of current financial markets is their willingness
to lend to the federal government on favorable terms, despite a huge budget
deficit, a fiscal trajectory that everyone knows is unsustainable and the
failure of our political leaders to reach a consensus on how to change
course. This can’t go on forever — that much is clear.
Less obvious, however, is how far we are from the day of reckoning.
Winston Churchill famously remarked that “Americans can always be
counted on to do the right thing, after they have exhausted all other
possibilities.” That seems to capture the attitude of the bond market today.
It trusts our leaders to get the government’s fiscal house in order,
eventually, and is waiting patiently while they exhaust the alternatives.
But such confidence in American rectitude will not last forever. The
more we delay, the bigger the risk that we follow the path of Greece, Ireland
and Portugal. I don’t know how long we have before the bond market turns
on the United States, but I would prefer not to run the experiment to find
out.
•
So those are the three questions that puzzle me most as I read the
daily news. If you find an economist who says he knows the answers, listen
carefully, but be skeptical of everything you hear.
1
The New York Times, October 22, 2011
Four Nations, Four Lessons
By N. GREGORY MANKIW
AS the economy languishes, politicians and pundits are debating what
to do next. When we look around the world, it’s hard to find positive role
models. But as we search for answers, it is useful to keep in mind those
fates that we would like to avoid.
The recent economic histories of four nations are noteworthy: France,
Greece, Japan and Zimbabwe. Each illustrates a kind of policy mistake that
could, if we are not careful, presage the future of the United States
economy. Think of them as the four horsemen of the economic apocalypse.
Let’s start with Zimbabwe. If there were an award for the world’s
worst economic policy, it might well have won it several times over the past
decade. In particular, in 2008 and 2009, it experienced truly spectacular
hyperinflation. Prices rose so fast that the central bank eventually printed
100 trillion-dollar notes for people to carry. The nation has since
abandoned using its own currency, but you can still buy one of those notes
as a novelty item for about $5 (American, that is).
Some may find it hard to imagine that the United States would ever
go down this route. But reckless money creation is apparently a concern of
Gov. Rick Perry of Texas, who is seeking the Republican nomination for
president. He suggested in August that it would be “almost treasonous” if
Ben S. Bernanke, chairman of the Federal Reserve, were to print too much
money before the election. Mr. Perry is not alone in his concerns. Many on
the right fear that the Fed’s recent policies aimed at fighting high
unemployment will mainly serve to ignite excessive inflation.
Mr. Bernanke, however, is less worried about the United States
turning into Zimbabwe than he is about it turning into Japan.
Those old enough to remember the 1980s will recall that Japan used
to be an up-and-coming economic superpower. Many people then worried
2
(too much, in my view) that Japan’s rapid growth was a threat to prosperity
in the United States, in much the same way that many people worry today
(too much, in my view) about rapid growth in China.
The concerns about Japanese hegemony came to a quick end after
bubbles in the real estate and stock markets burst in the early 1990s. Since
then, Japan has struggled to regain its footing. Critics of the Bank of Japan
say it has been too focused on quelling phantom inflationary threats and
insufficiently concerned about restoring robust economic growth.
One of those critics was Mr. Bernanke, before he became Fed
chairman. Watching Japanese timidity and failures has surely made him
more willing to experiment with unconventional forms of monetary policy
in the aftermath of our own financial crisis.
The economists in the Obama administration are also well aware of
the Japanese experience. That is one reason they are pushing for more
stimulus spending to prop up the aggregate demand for goods and services.
Yet this fiscal policy comes with its own risks. The more we rely on
deficit spending to keep the economy afloat, the more we risk the kind of
sovereign debt crisis we have witnessed in Greece over the past year. The
Standard & Poor’s downgrade of United States debt over the summer is a
portent of what could lie ahead. In the long run, we have to pay our debts —
or face dire consequences.
To be sure, the bond market doesn’t seem particularly worried about
the solvency of the federal government. It is still willing to lend to the
United States at low rates of interest. But the same thing was true of Greece
four years ago. Once the bond market starts changing its mind, the verdict
can be swift, and can lead to a vicious circle of rising interest rates,
increasing debt service and budget deficits, and falling confidence.
Bond markets are now giving the United States the benefit of the
doubt, partly because other nations look even riskier, and partly in the
belief that we will, in time, get our fiscal house in order. The big political
question is how.
3
The nation faces a fundamental decision about priorities. To maintain
current levels of taxation, we will need to substantially reduce spending on
the social safety net, including Social Security, Medicare, Medicaid and the
new health care program sometimes called Obamacare. Alternatively, we
can preserve the current social safety net and raise taxes substantially to
pay for it. Or we may choose a combination of spending cuts and tax
increases. This brings us to the last of our cautionary tales: France.
Here are two facts about the French economy. First, gross domestic
product per capita in France is 29 percent less than it is in the United
States, in large part because the French work many fewer hours over their
lifetimes than Americans do. Second, the French are taxed more than
Americans. In 2009, taxes were 24 percent of G.D.P. in the United States
but 42 percent in France.
Economists debate whether higher taxation in France and other
European nations is the cause of the reduced work effort and incomes
there. Perhaps it is something else entirely — a certain joie de vivre that
escapes the nose-to-the-grindstone American culture.
We may soon be running a natural experiment to find out. If
American policy makers don’t rein in entitlement spending over the next
several decades, they will have little choice but to raise taxes close to
European levels. We can then see whether the next generation of Americans
spends less time at work earning a living and more time sipping espresso in
outdoor cafes.
1
The New York Times, March 4, 2012
Capital Gains, Ordinary Income and Shades of Gray
By N. GREGORY MANKIW
WHAT is carried interest? And why does it get the tax treatment it
does?
These arcane questions are usually reserved for the green-eyeshade
crowd. And for good reason: they can be so bewildering that they seem to
be taken from an I.Q. test written just for accountants. But because they
concern a few very high-income individuals, including the presidential
candidate Mitt Romney, for whom I am an adviser, they have been getting
broader attention lately. So let’s examine the issue.
Throughout almost the entire history of the United States income tax,
the tax rate on capital gains has been lower than that on ordinary income.
Today, the top rate is 15 percent for capital gains and 35 percent for
ordinary income. There are good reasons for this — including, for example,
the fact that capital gains are not indexed for inflation. But put that aside. If
we are going to tax capital gains at a lower rate, one question necessarily
arises: What is a capital gain, and how can we distinguish it from ordinary
income?
The answer seems simple. If you have a job, the money you are paid
for your work is ordinary income. If you buy an asset at one time and sell it
later for a higher price, the profit you made from holding it is a capital gain.
But is it really that easy? Consider five examples, and see if you can
identify what is ordinary income and what is a capital gain:
• Abe buys a vacation home for his family for $800,000. Some years
later, when his children have grown and left home, he sells it for $1 million.
He makes $200,000.
• Bob is a real estate investor. After scouring the market for the best
investment opportunities, he buys a house for $800,000 that he believes is
2
undervalued. A few years later, he sells it at $1 million, for a profit of
$200,000.
• Carl is a real estate investor and a carpenter. He buys a dilapidated
house for $800,000. After spending his weekends fixing it up, he sells it a
couple of years later for $1 million. Once again, the profit is $200,000.
• Dan is a real estate investor and a carpenter, but he is short of
capital. He approaches his friend, Ms. Moneybags, and they become
partners. Together, they buy a dilapidated house for $800,000 and sell it
later for $1 million. She puts up the money, and he spends his weekends
fixing up the house. They divide the $200,000 profit equally.
• Earl is a carpenter. Ms. Moneybags buys a dilapidated house for
$800,000 and hires Earl to fix it up. After paying Earl $100,000 for his
services, Ms. Moneybags sells the home for $1 million, for a profit of
$100,000.
How much capital gains and ordinary income do we attribute to Abe,
Bob, Carl, Dan and Earl? (To keep things simple, assume that Ms.
Moneybags is untaxed. Think of her as running a pension fund or university
endowment.)
Let’s take the easy cases first. It seems clear that Abe has a capital
gain. His profit of $200,000 comes from simply holding an asset over time.
And it seems equally clear that Earl’s $100,000 is ordinary income. He is
being paid for providing his services.
But between these cases, the situation gets murky. Bob and Carl are
being rewarded in part for the time they spend, but the tax law treats both
as having earned entirely capital gains. The tax code does not count the
time that Bob spent looking for investments as employment and his gain as
taxable labor compensation, even though some of it arguably is. Nor does it
try to tax Carl’s sweat equity as labor compensation.
This brings us to Dan and his partnership with Ms. Moneybags. The
tax law treats this partnership as exactly equivalent to Carl’s situation. In
this case, however, the $200,000 capital gain is divided into halves: some
3
of it goes to Ms. Moneybags, who provided the cash, and some goes to Dan,
who provided the sweat equity. Once again, nothing is treated as ordinary
income.
In some ways, this treatment makes sense. After all, Dan is doing half
of what Carl did, so why should he have to pay a higher tax rate than Carl
did on that half of his income? On the other hand, it seems that Dan is
getting off easy. Dan does not seem very different from Earl, because both
are getting $100,000 for fixing up the house.
If these examples leave your head spinning, you are not alone.
Economists and tax lawyers who study these issues are unsure about the
best way to handle these situations in practice.
Here is where carried interest enters the picture. Carried interest
from a private equity partnership is like the income that Dan earns from his
real estate partnership. In this case, however, Dan is not a carpenter but a
specialist in business turnarounds. The partnership does not buy
dilapidated houses to fix up and sell; it buys troubled businesses to fix up
and sell. And just as Dan the carpenter can treat his share of the
partnership income as a capital gain, Dan the business specialist can do the
same.
Critics of current law think it is unfair that these private equity
partners are taxed at capital gains rates, whereas other high-income
individuals like doctors and lawyers pay the much higher tax rates for
ordinary income. It is a reasonable point, and some reform may well be
appropriate. But as the tax situations of Abe through Earl illustrate, it is not
obvious what the best approach would be. Not all problems have easy
answers.
No comments:
Post a Comment